medicare for all

Your Insurance Is Getting Disrupted — With or Without Medicare for All

There is no alternative to a radical alternative. Photo: Dana Neely/Getty Images

The American health-care system is a vast, dilapidated mansion with stairways that lead to nowhere, floorboards full of termites, walls that bleed asbestos, shattered windows, a broken furnace, flooded basement, and the unfriendliest of ghosts.

In other words, it is a hellacious, irrational structure that would be cheaper to tear down and rebuild than renovate, repair, or even maintain.

But the existing structure works well for the exterminator, space-heater, and ghostbuster industries, all of which have strong lobbies (and would suffer a sharp decline in profitability if America transitioned to a single-heater mansion that was ghost-free at the point of service). And since millions of ordinary Americans don’t even have access to the mansion, those who are privileged enough to enjoy its modest protections — especially those who’ve secured a relatively dry and warm spot within the crumbling structure — tend to express satisfaction with the status quo in opinion surveys. So, when voters are told that they can have cheaper, more comprehensive protection from a brand-new mansion — so long as they accept a modest increase in property taxes, which would be fully offset by savings on utilities and maintenance — many evince skepticism. And once Big Ghostbuster starts airing fear-mongering ads about how tearing down the existing structure will turn U.S. into Venezuela, that skepticism is liable to harden into opposition.

All of which is to say: There are virtually no good substantive arguments for preferring incremental improvements to the American health-care system over simply replacing it with a well-designed, single-payer one. But there are some decent political arguments for such a preference.

Unfortunately, politicians aren’t usually comfortable saying, “I support a suboptimal policy because I am afraid of taking on the special interests who oppose the optimal one, and also believe that voters are too ignorant to recognize where their true interests lie, anyway.” So many politicians will simply recast the political downsides of single-payer as substantive defects instead.

For example, some moderate Democrats oppose Medicare for All on the grounds that such a system would be too expensive, and that people who like their employer-sponsored coverage should be able to keep it. Neither of these complaints make sense in substantive terms.

Under our existing system, the United States spends several times more than similar nations on health-care administration, pharmaceuticals, and physicians’ salaries. In return, Americans enjoy the 29th best health-care system in the world (just behind the Czech Republic’s) according to the Lancet.

Source:: Source: Harvard T.H. Chan School of Public Health, Harvard Global Health Institute, London School of Economics. Credit: Rebecca Coleman/Harvard

In 2018, Canada spent roughly 11 percent of its GDP on health care, which was enough to provide all of its citizens with premium-free access to the world’s 14th highest performing health-care system. That same year, the United States spent roughly 18 percent of its GDP on health care — which, in our system, was not sufficient to provide any form of insurance to nearly 30 million Americans, nor to prevent more than 50 percent of our people from delaying or forgoing medical care due to affordability concerns.

The source of these divergent outcomes isn’t hard to discern: Canada has a single-payer system that enables it to save money on redundant administration, and to dictate reimbursement rates to medical providers. America, by contrast, subsidizes the private insurance industry (and its wasteful administrative bureaucracies), while allowing physicians’ cartels and hospital monopolies to dictate their own pay rates to private providers. Thus, a competently designed single-payer system would be less expensive than maintaining our existing one.

For this reason (among others), letting people keep their current employer-provided insurance is not actually an option. As the boomer generation ages, it’s consuming more health-care services, thereby driving up the price of such services. Meanwhile, the burgeoning demand for drugs that ease the burdens of senescence is leading Big Pharma to roll out exorbitantly expensive new medicines. As a result, the costs of health care in America aren’t just exceptionally high, but also increasing exceptionally fast.

And that’s a major problem for American employers. As Axios illustrates:

For big employers, the total cost of providing their workers with health-care benefits will rise 5 percent in 2019. That’s twice the rate of wage increases, and three times general inflation, according to the Society for Human Resource Management (SHRM).

Our employer-provided health-insurance system has long been a burden on corporate America. Shortly before the Great Recession, General Motors estimated that the cost of providing its workers with medical benefits added $1,500 to the price of every new automobile it produced, putting the company at a competitive disadvantage relative to its peers in nations with more socialized health-care systems (i.e, Germany and Japan). But as the graying of the boomers pushes prices ever higher, our “free market” health-care system will become an existential threat to many a free enterprise. Put simply, more and more firms will be unable to both retain profitability and provide their employees with decent coverage. Already, the quality of employer-sponsored insurance is steadily declining, as businesses pass rising costs onto their workers. And plans are only going to grow more austere as time goes on: A SHRM survey from 2018 found more than half of large companies plan to steer their employees toward more “virtual” or “telehealth” health-care options, as a means of controlling labor costs.

Thus, under our current system, the vast majority of Americans who like their employer-provided insurance can’t keep it. Even if they do keep their networks, their benefits are going to decline in value. And as firms scramble to cut costs, millions will be forced to switch plans entirely. As Matt Bruenig notes, as of 2014, more than a quarter of Michiganders with employer-sponsored coverage were forced to switch their plans annually:

A study from the University of Michigan tracked insurance churn directly by surveying Michiganders in 2014 about their health insurance situation and then following up with survey participants 12 months later. The amount of insurance churn they picked up was even higher than I would have imagined.

 

Among those who had employer-sponsored insurance in 2014, only 72 percent were continuously enrolled in that insurance for the next 12 months. This means that 28 percent of people on an employer plan were not on that same plan 1 year later. You like your employer health plan? You better cross your fingers because 1 in 4 people on employer plans will come off their plan in the next 12 months.

It’s clear then, that opposing radical changes to our existing health-care system — because such change would be too expensive and disruptive to people’s existing coverage — doesn’t make much sense. “It would cost a lot of money to rebuild our dilapidated mansion (albeit, less than it will cost to heat a giant home with broken windows and poor insulation)” is not a good argument against rebuilding a dilapidated mansion; neither is “some people aren’t getting rained on yet (but almost certainly will, if current trends continue.”

But human beings are subject to status quo bias. And those who profit off dysfunctional status quo systems can use the broader populace’s loss aversion to their advantage. Meanwhile, bringing the costs of all health coverage in the United States onto Uncle Sam’s books would (almost certainly) require raising taxes. And while voters might be better off trading their ever-rising premiums for a modest tax hike, when private insurers raise premiums, voters are unlikely to hold Democratic lawmakers responsible. When Democratic lawmakers vote to raise taxes, by contrast, they put targets on their backs. Similarly, when Americans lose their coverage due to churn in the employer-provided insurance market, the newly dissatisfied don’t (typically) blame the Democratic Party. If Democrats voted to directly abolish their coverage, however, they almost certainly would.

None of this means that Democrats shouldn’t try to liberate Americans from the haunted, ramshackle health-care system they call home. But it does mean that progressives must strive to raise the public’s awareness of the rising costs, and coverage disruptions, that will be required under our existing system. And every time a Democrat describes Medicare for All as exceptionally expensive — or exceptionally disruptive to existing coverage — they make that task more difficult.

U.S. Can’t Afford ‘Good Employer-Provided Insurance for All’